Lecture 27.
Measuring trade liberalisation effects
What we want to learn about this topic
- to examine some of the influential studies on the likely gains from further agricultural trade liberalisation
- to examine some reasons why modellers reach different conclusions in terms of welfare outcomes and why estimates of the gains from a Doha Round agreement have been shrinking.
This lecture summary should be read in conjunction with the later lecture summary which examines specifically the impact of agricultural protectionism and liberalisation on developing countries.
Short introduction to the issues
Wide range of projected welfare changes from agricultural liberalization
Examples are given in the Powerpoint slides. Such differences in results are disconcerting to policymakers. Why such differences? How much weight should be
put on the results of one individual model? Are some models superior to others? What are main characteristics of
models which mean some might be taken more seriously than others?
Different types of model are used
- Single or multi-commodity model
- Effects of simultaneous liberalisation are different from the sum of the effects of liberalising
each commodity separately because of the important interdependencies which exist between agricultural commodities.
These interdependencies occur with respect to both the supply and demand sides, and can be of both a competitive
and complementary kind.
For example, a relative reduction in the price of an individual grain crop will cause farmers to substitute other
crops consistent with rotation and other technical requirements. However, if the prices of all crops are reduced
simultaneously, substitution effects will be negligible and the main effect on supply will come through changes
in farmers' use of variable inputs and subsequent changes in yields.
Another important example is the consequence of feed/livestock interdependence. If both feed and livestock prices
are simultaneously reduced, the impact of the livestock price reduction on livestock supply will be much reduced
compared to the situation where feed prices are assumed to remain unaltered. Similarly, the impact of grain price
reductions on the export surplus of grains will be indeterminate when livestock prices and thus livestock demand
for feed can vary.
- Partial or general equilibrium
- Low computing power meant that in the past most models were partial equilibrium. Computable
general equilibrium (CGE) models are now much more practicable but when should one be preferred? PE models often
allow much more detailed implementation of policies, CGE models often much cruder. CGE models may be difficult
to interpret. But if the change is likely to have economy-wide effects, then CGE models are to be preferred.
Example: suppose EU liberalises its ag policy. Ag exports fall and EU runs a larger balance of payments deficit.
Value of euro falls. This boosts growth in the nonfarm sector which, if unemployment exists, may produce much bigger
welfare gains than those observed in the agricultural markets alone (i.e. the classic welfare triangle effects).
Yet such effects would be ignored in partial equilibrium models.
- Partial equilibrium Modellers often confine their model coverage to the main temperate zone commodities, thus
mexcluding tropical, Mediterranean and processed products. If these products are important for some countries, then
the effects of agricultural support or trade liberalisation may be over- or under-estimated. EU studies which look
at the effect of CAP reform on individual Member States often suffer from this problem. By definition, general equilibrium models do not suffer from this problem as all economic sectors are included.
- Econometric or general equilibrium
Econometric models are usually applied to single commodity or multi commodity partial equilibrium studies. Responses to price changes are based on ex post observations of what happened in the past. Most of the recent global analyses are based on computable general equilibrium models. These models use databases which capture all flows and interdependencies in the global economy, and assume that neoclassical optimising behaviour drives responses to price changes. The magnitude of these responses is estimated from econometric studies of past behaviour summarised in the size of the elasticitiy values used as parameters by the model (e.g., demand elasticities, substitution elasticities between inputs in production, substitution between different sources of supply such as domestic production vs. imports).
Most CGE models use the GTAP database, a global database maintained by a consortium of government agencies and international research institutions. There is also a GTAP model which has been widely applied to analyse the implications of further agricultural trade liberalisation in the Doha Round. CGE models are calibrated models, that is, they are deliberately made consistent with a single year's data which is assumed to represent a long-run equilibrium. It is more difficult to validate the results of a CGE model because unlike econometric models we have no information about the distribution of errors.
Many models are comparative static. They are built on data for an historical base period, and the policy experiment
is to ask what would have happened in that period if some one or more particular policies had been different (e.g.
what would have happened if the rate of tariff protection had been 0 per cent rather than 50 per cent?). The usefulness
of these comparative static experiments is that the results, when expressed in percentage terms, can give us an
idea of what the impact of a similar policy if it were introduced today or in the future might be. Dynamic models
attempt to project a baseline, i.e. an assumption about the state of the world under particular assumptions into
the future, and then ask how that baseline would be different if a particular policy change were introduced at
a given time. Dynamic models have the advantage that they can trace the path of change over time, which may involve
overshooting and then convergence to a new equilibrium. They have the drawback of the added complexity needed
to be able to model the way the world changes from one time period to the next. The FAPRI-Ireland model is an example
of a dynamic (partial equilibrium) model which is used for the simulation of policy changes affecting Irish agriculture.
See their analysis of the impact of decoupling on
Irish agriculture for an example of price overshooting in the beef market.
Model and parameter assumptions may be different
The key parameters in partial equilibrium studies include the base period used which can
influence the initial levels of protection assumed, the size of the behavioural responses by producers and consumers
(as measured by price elasticities) as well as price transmission elasticities. Nearly all global models assume
perfectly competitive markets, although imperfectly competitive behaviour may be more realistic and might yield
quite different results.
- Base period and initial levels of protection
- It is the reduction in protection as a result of policy liberalisation which drives the
model results, and the initial level of protection is clearly important.
Given the importance of non-tariff barriers to trade, most studies use tariff equivalent measures derived by taking
the difference between domestic and world price levels such as the PSE or the Nominal Assistance Coefficient .
Even for the same time period, there is a surprising diversity in the values used by different researchers, which
reflect in part the complications in making such comparisons.
Because world prices fluctuate much more than domestic prices, protection levels vary considerably from year to
year, so the base period chosen for the study will also influence the results.
- The magnitude of the world price effects of any given liberalisation policy will depend
on the responses of producers, consumers and other governments. The behaviour of producers and consumers is summarised
in the supply and demand elasticities used by the researcher. Because accurate information is lacking, a common
approach is to parameterise them and to test the sensitivity of the results to these changes.
- Taking account of complementary policies
- Estimation of producer supply response is further complicated in countries where price
support is accompanied by supply controls. In principle, it is possible that the removal of price support and supply
controls at the same time could lead to an increase rather than the expected decrease in supply. If the modeller
has not tried to incorporate this additional effect into his or her model, these results will differ from someone
who has.
- Price transmission elasticities
- The response of other governments to the initial increase in world prices is given by the
price transmission elasticities assumed. A price transmission elasticity of one implies that other governments
permit changes in world prices to be reflected in domestic prices on a one-for one basis or, in other words, it
assumes that whatever policy stance they originally adopted (as measured by the level of protection in place) remains
unchanged. The other extreme is a price transmission elasticity of zero, implying that other governments hold their
domestic prices unchanged even when world prices change. The higher the weighted price transmission elasticity
of those governments not taking part in the initial liberalisation, the lower the world price effect and the higher
the trade effect of the policy change. Price transmission elasticities can either be assumed or estimated from
time series data.
- If the modeller attempts a future-oriented projection, this may include attempting to project
not only future prices and quantities but also the future stance of government policy in
response to the implied changes in budget costs or farm incomes. Where the level
of protection in a model is not assumed exogenously (for example, by assuming that the same rate of protection
will apply in the future as in the base year) but is itself a function of model variables, this is referred to
as endogenising policy. But it is clear that if an attempt is first made to project the likely
level of protection in the future, and then the model is solved to reflect the removal
of this likely level, then the results will differ from a standard comparative static experiment in which the level
of protection is assumed to be equal to the base year period.
Scenario assumptions may be different
Even where modellers make use of the same model and the same parameter and modelling assumptions,
the results may differ because the scenarios being modelled (i.e. the questions being asked) may differ. Even
where the question being asked seems the same, the way the scenario is implemented may differ. Thus it is very
important to interpret the results of a study in terms of the scenario being modelled. For example:
- some studies set out to model the impact of complete agricultural trade liberalisation,
others may model only a partial removal or reduction of support
- some studies might model only a reduction in agricultural support, while others might model
multisectoral liberalisation including reductions in tariffs on manufactured goods. World price effects resulting
from multisectoral liberalisation are typically dampened compared to those from agricultural liberalisation alone,
in part because the removal of protection to manufacturing reduces the relative price of manufactured goods, inducing
a shift in consumption away from agricultural to manufacturing products in national markets. Thus the excess supply
curve of agricultural products moves to the left (or the import demand curve moves to the right), dampening the
impact of liberalisation on world agricultural prices compared to a partial liberalisation scenario.
- some studies might model the reduction in support in OECD countries only, others might
assume that all countries participate in the removal of tariff protection.
- suppose a study says it is modelling the removal of support to agriculture. Is this all
support (including Green Box support and de minimis
AMS support) or is it modelling the effect of a WTO Agreement to reduce AMS ceilings to zero? Because the latter
scenario does not require all support to be removed, the former study would produce larger results compared to
the latter.
- suppose a study says it is modelling the impact of the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture
on global food markets. It therefore reduces all tariffs by 36% (or 24% for developing countries) which was the
average reduction agreed in the Uruguay Round. But, for many developing countries, applied tariffs are much lower
than bound tariffs and thus were not necessarily reduced by this amount. We also know that because of 'dirty tariffication'
even in developed countries the actual tariff reduction was often less than what had been promised. Thus, a study
which took the formal Uruguay Round reductions would over-estimate the actual impact of the amount of trade liberalisation
which did occur.
Another important issue in all simulations is the counterfactual, i.e. what assumption is the modeller making about the reference scenario against which the policy
scenario is being compared? Specifying the counterfactual is a very important part of policy modelling. For example,
suppose you were asked to estimate the impact on Irish agriculture if EU agricultural policy eliminated market
price support under the Common Agricultural Policy. Your answer would be very different depending on whether you
assumed that the CAP status quo could continue or whether you believed that, in the absence of CAP market price
support, some alternative support mechanism for farmers would be put in place. In comparative static models, the
counterfactual is implicity the policy structure which was in place in the base period of the model. In dynamic
models, the counterfactual is more explicit and is built into the baseline against which the outcome of the policy
simulation is compared.
Reading suggestions
Empirical studies
Martin, W. and Anderson, K., 2006. The Doha Agenda negotiations on agriculture: what could they deliver?, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 88, 5 (2006), 1211-1218 (access through Trinity Library only)
Taylor, L. 2006, Modelling the Impact of Trade Liberalisation: a Critique of General Equilibrium Models, Oxfam.
Surveys and commentaries
Bouet, A., 2006, How much will agricultural trade liberalization help the poor? Comparing global trade models, IFPRI Research Brief No. 5, Washington, D.C., International Food Policy Research Institute.
Elliott, Kimberley Ann, 2006. Can Doha Still Deliver on the Development Agenda? Policy Briefs in International Economics No. PBO6-5, Washington, D.C., Institute for International Economics.
Ackerman, F., 2005. The Shrinking Gains from Trade: A critical assessment of Doha Round projections, Global Development and Environment Institute, Working Paper 05-01, Tufts University.
The Economist, 'Weighed in the balance: global trade', 8 December 2005.
(short survey of how the estimated gains from liberalisation have shrunk over time)
FAO 2005. Trade policy simulation models: Estimating global impacts of agricultural trade policy reform in the Doha Round, FAO Trade Policy Technical Note # 13, FAO, Rome. [download]
(20-page briefing which explores why model results differ and explains the key assumptions made by modellers in generating simulation results).
Supplementary reading
Anderson , K. and Martin W., eds., 2006. Agricultural Trade Reform and the Doha Development Agenda, World Bank and Palgrave Macmillan
(see
especially Anderson, K., Martin, W. and van der Mensbrugge, D., Market and welfare implications of Doha Reform Scenarios, Chapter 12 and Hertel, T. and Keeney, R., 2006. What is at Stake: The relative importance of import barrie rs, export subsidies and domestic support, Chapter 2)
(Note these readings cover similar ground to the AJAE article above at greater length. To download the tables and figures, you will need to click here and look for Chapters 2 and 12)
Congressional Budget Office, 2005, The Effects of Liberalizing World Agricultural Trade: A Survey, Congress of the United States.
(short, 33-page paper which discusses in order the total cost of policies that distort agricultural trade, considerations with partial liberalisation, and distributional issues).
Web resources
The Global Subsidies Initiative has a very useful page which brings together a series of links on why model results have changed.